• 16004_11.13_000006085152XSmall

    What Should Government Pay For?

    Nov 13 • Economic Debates, Economic History, Government, Macroeconomic Measurement • 335 Views

    Topping its front page with “CUT, RAISE, RAISE, LOWER, REPEAL, SCRAP, CUT, CUT,” The Wall Street Journal told readers some of the new deficit commission’s proposals. 1) For defense spending, the cut would be $100 billion. 2) The Social Security age would rise to 69 by 2075. 3) The gas tax would go up 15 cents. 4) The corporate tax rate would go down to 26%. 5) The alternative minimum tax would be repealed. 6) There would no longer be deductions for mortgages over 500k. 7) The federal work force would be cut by 10%. 8) Farm subsidies would drop by $3 billion.

    For each proposal, already, a mountain of pro and con opinions is building. For example, just for changing the Social Security retirement age, the list of arguments on both sides is long because affluence, health, job history, and gender all relate to how Social Security impacts you. Supporters point out that when Social Security was passed in 1935, the average life span was, at 61.7, 3.3 years less than the retirement age. In 2035, 20% of the U.S. population is projected to be 65 or older. Responding, economist Paul Krugman says, “working until you’re 69…is a lot harder…for…Americans who still do physical labor.” Also, he says that high earners live longer.

    The Economic Lesson

    Defined on Planet Money, a public good is “something that we all need that will make our lives better, but the market will not and cannot provide.”  Podcast examples included lighthouses and autopsies.

    Should government pay only for “public goods?” We would not have a deficit problem.

    No Comments on What Should Government Pay For?

    Read More
  • 16002_11.12_000007395743XSmall

    Free Trade

    Nov 12 • Developing Economies, International Trade and Finance • 476 Views

    KORUS has been in the news. The Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, negotiated in 2007 but not ratified by Congress, was in trouble. One reason was Ford.

    With a 1% share of the South Korean car market, U.S. automakers want more. One of the bigger sellers of Ford vehicles in South Korea complained about import taxes that make his vehicles so much more expensive than Korean made cars. Ford also said that unfairly high South Korean emissions and safety standards on imports prevent them from competing.

    I guess all of this reminds me of China and our chicken feet and Italy and Pecorino cheese. When we put a tariff on their tires, China retaliated against our chicken feet. When the EU unfairly treated our bananas, we taxed their cheese.

    The significance? Free trade agreements increase U.S. exports. They stimulate our economic growth. Also, though, whether in South Korea or the U.S., they challenge specific domestic producers and can eliminate domestic jobs. Free trade is one of those issues that has been debated for centuries and will remain controversial.

    The Economic Lesson

    Combining Adam Smith and David Ricardo, we can see why most economists support free trade. In a factory, Adam Smith says specialize through division of labor. When each worker has a specific task, output multiplies. Increasing output requires bigger markets in order to sell what has been produced.  As mass production enables us to move from local markets to regional specialization to free world trade, as David Ricardo explained, the world benefits.

    In a 2006 survey, 87.5% of all PH.D members of the American Economic Association said yes to free trade by agreeing that “the U.S. should eliminate remaining tariffs and other barriers to trade.”

    No Comments on Free Trade

    Read More
  • 16000_11.11_000012487089XSmall

    The Cost of a Corn Flake

    Nov 11 • Businesses, Demand, Supply, and Markets, International Trade and Finance • 418 Views

    Telling us that corn prices are soaring, NPR asked, “Why Not Corn Flakes?” After all, approximately 13 ounces of an 18-ounce box of corn flakes is corn. The corn, though, only adds close to 4 cents to the price. So, even if corn prices continue to soar, a 33% increase means less than 2 cents more for our flakes.

    As we have heard from Michael Pollan, corn touches our food supply in countless ways. We might see skinnier animals being sold by farmers who are paying more for corn feed and higher prices for beef, pork, and chicken. It is also possible that Coke and Pepsi will substitute sucrose for high-fructose corn syrup. Citing higher commodity costs, McDonald’s just announced it was raising menu prices.

    The Economic Lesson

    A classic economic scenario, drought in Russia and too much rain in some U.S. corn fields shifted the corn supply curve to the left. Meanwhile, congressional ethanol mandates and some panic buying from Asia are shifting the demand curve to the right. Supply down. Demand up. The resut? Higher prices.

    You know what follows. Through the wonder of the market, the invisible hand tells farmers to plant more corn. 

     

    No Comments on The Cost of a Corn Flake

    Read More
  • 15998_7.7_000004061067XSmall

    Venezuela’s Prices

    Nov 10 • Businesses, Demand, Supply, and Markets, Regulation • 434 Views

    You might find it interesting to ponder the implications of the sign in a Venezuelan shopping mall which I saw on Harvard’s N. Gregory Mankiw’s blog. Called Mercado Bicentenario, the store was a part of a chain that had recently been nationalized by the Venezuelan government. The sign said the following:

    Description of the product: Diana oil

    Fair Price: 4,73 Bfs

    Capitalist Price: 7,00 Bfs.

    % of Savings: 32%

    The Economic Lesson

    Please consider for a moment what you think when you hear that a t-shirt is $10. What if the price is $50? As market determined prices, $10 and $50 convey a message to sellers and buyers.

    Market (or as stated in Venezuela, “capitalist”) prices provide crucial information. They tell us about value and efficiency and affordability. They let consumers and businesses and government decide what to do, what not to do, and what they can do better.

    A government established price conveys no signals to sellers and buyers. The supply side can no longer determine a connection among price, profits, and using resources efficiently. On the demand side, consumers can neither assess quality nor indicate what they want and do not want. 

    The long lines, pajama tops without buttons, and grouchy salespeople that characterized the former Soviet Union are perfect examples of what happens in a centrally controlled economy.

     

     

    No Comments on Venezuela’s Prices

    Read More
  • 15996_5.31_000009096130XSmall

    Cotton and Crocodiles

    Nov 9 • Businesses, Demand, Supply, and Markets, Developing Economies, Financial Markets, Government, Innovation, International Trade and Finance • 426 Views

    A Malaysian proverb tells us, “Don’t think there are no crocodiles because the water is calm.” Looking at cotton markets, perhaps we should remember the crocodiles.

    According to The Wall Street Journal, cotton prices are soaring. Speaking as economists, it all sounds so logical. On the supply side, in Pakistan and China, weather was bad. The economic response? Move that supply curve upward to the left. On the demand side, with the economy improving, consumers are buying more clothing so move the demand curve to the right. A decrease in supply and an increase in demand have only one result: higher prices for our t-shirts.

    Beneath the surface, though, so much more is happening. In an earlier post, we noted the cost of policies that save domestic jobs in the textile and apparel industries. The cost of saving 168,786 jobs is $33,629,000,000 or $199,241 per job.

    Furthermore, a recent Planet Money podcast tells us that U.S. farmers are not only subsidized and protected by tariffs but also that the U.S. government began to subsidize Brazilian cotton farmers after a World Trade Organization dispute.

    Next, throw cotton speculators and congressmen into this pot with demand, supply, weather, tariffs, China, Pakistan, subsidized farmers in Lubbock, Texas and Brazil. Don’t we have lots of crocodiles in a seemingly logical world of cotton buyers and sellers?

    The Economic Lesson

    A Yale graduate, Eli Whitney could not find a job. His one offer was to become the tutor in Georgia for the Nathaniel Green family. Urged by Yale president Ezra Stiles to say yes, he went. The rest is history.

    It all began with never-ending discussions with Mrs. Green and her estate manager about the difficulty of cleaning cotton. The result, in 1793, was Whitney’s invention, the cotton gin, and the birth of an industry.

    No Comments on Cotton and Crocodiles

    Read More